CfER FAQ #1

Q. What is Proportional Representation?

A. Proportional Representation ("PR") means using a type of election system in which the overall results are proportional to the votes.

E.g., in a PR system, if a party gets 30% of the votes, they get 30% of the seats in the legislature, if they get 5% of the votes, they get 5% of the seats. In contrast, winner-take-all systems (such as those in the USA and England) make it almost impossible for smaller parties to win seats, since they have to get 51% of the vote in a district to win a seat. As a result, although Democrats and Republicans make up only about 79% of the electorate, they hold more than 99% of the seats in Congress and in state legislatures.

PR is used in the vast majority of the world's stable democracies. It is a proven system. In fact, most established democracies that don't use PR are ex-colonies of England that just adopted the English winner-take-all system. And PR is used in the United States today, though not too many people know about it.

There are different types of PR systems. PR is used in local, state and federal elections, government and non-government elections, partisan and non-partisan elections.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #9

Q. Isn't PR really complicated?

A. The process of choosing a legislative body by vote - PR or otherwise - is inherently complicated. It can be made very simple if we decide to surrender all of our power of choice to redistricting committees and other political insiders. But by accepting a small amount of additional complexity, voters can increase their power dramatically. There are several PR methods that have been proven to work for decades by millions of voters.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #10

Q. How does PR actually work?

A. There can be a number of different ways to count choice voting (nonpartisan PR) elections, but if you use the following approaches, you are on solid ground.

FOR A HAND COUNT

Check out "Procedures for a Hand-Counted Choice Voting Election"

FOR A COMPUTER COUNT

A computer count is much like a hand count, except that:

1. A candidate is allowed to get "surplus votes" -- votes beyond the winning threshold. Whenever this happens, the computer transfers part of each ballot to other candidates, as directed by the rankings on each ballot. E.g. The threshold is 2000. Candidate A recieves 4000 votes. Half of each vote is transferred from A to other candidates, so that he has 2000 total votes. DemoChoice is a website that can conduct such counts.

2. Duplicate rankings may be allowed.
The vote will be split equally among those candidates with duplicate rankings. E.g. The voter marks candidates A, B, and C as her #1 choice. The each get 1/3 of her vote. If candidate A is later declared defeated, then B & C will now each get 1/2 of her vote.

VARIATIONS

There are a number of variations that are possible. The rules above are only meant to show you one way to do a count, not every possible variation.

See CVD's web site for some possible wording for municipal elections.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #11

Q. Isn't PR expensive to administer?

A. PR methods are not substantially more expensive to administer than any other election method, and the cost would just be lost in the background noise of voter pamphlet costs, registration database maintenance, and so on.

There are sometimes costs associated with adopting a PR method if the voting equipment can't already handle it.

The costs of PR must be weighed against the cost of bad representation: if PR can prevent a single pork-barrel project - or an electricity crisis such as the one experienced in 2001 - it will quickly pay for itself.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #12

Q. What books or periodicals do you recommend to learn more about PR

A. Some of the best stuff is just in getting newsletters from CVD or your state level PR group. Contact them for more information on joining/subscribing to these newsletters. In addition, CVD regularly sends out email updates to interested parties. Email them to get on this list at: fairvote@compuserve.com.

Proportional Representation, The Case for a Better Election System, by Douglas Amy (Crescent Street Press, Northampton, MA, 1997). An excellent introduction to PR, this 42 page pamphlet is highly accessable. Can be ordered thru CVD (email: fairvote@compuserve.com) for only $3.00 a copy.

Real Choices, New Voices, by Douglas Amy (Columbia University Press, 1993). This book is an easy to read, excellent primer on PR. It may be available at your local library or bookstore, but if not, it is definitely available thru CVD, or at the Amazon & Barnes and Noble web-sites.

Fixing Elections, by Steven Hill. This is not about PR, but discusses why winner-take-all elections are a disservice to democracy.

Proportional Representation and Election Reform in Ohio, by Kathleen Barber (Ohio State University Press, 1995). Analyzes PR's use in the United States, with a focus on Ohio.

Seats and Votes, by Taagapera and Shugart. This one is tough reading unless you have a knack for math or don't mind skipping the math. But if you can get through it, it gives you a really thorough understanding how changing electoral rules can have a large impact on providing fair representation for all.

United States Electoral Systems; Their Impact on Women and Minorities, edited by Wilma Rule and Joseph F. Zimmerman (Praeger, 1992). Fairly accessible set of articles by different scholars, looking at how electoral systems affect women and minorities.

Is Democracy Fair? The Mathematics of Voting and Apportionment, written by Leslie Johnson Nielsen and Michael de Villiers (Key Curriculum Press, 1997)
P.O. Box 2304, Berkeley, CA 94702, (510) 548-2304 e-mail: editorial@keypress.com web site: http://www.keypress.com This is a textbook that explains all the major methods of vote counting and apportionment clearly and gives students plenty of encouragement to think about the pros and cons of each method.

Excursions in Modern Mathematics, Prentice Hall
This is an introductory college level math textbook. It has an entire section dealing with the mathematics of voting and different voting systems.
Companion Web Page

Finally, there is a large PR bibliography at a new web site developed by Professor Douglas Amy (author of Real Choices, New Voices) for citizens, activists, teachers and students who want to learn more about proportional representation elections. The PR Library includes a large number of articles with a US focus.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

FAQ #14 -- "What countries use Proportional Representation?"

WESTERN EUROPE
* Not using PR: UK, France, Vatican City
* The countries that do use PR are: Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Denmark, Finland, Germany, Greece, Iceland, Ireland, Italy (25% PR), Liechtenstein, Luxemborg, Malta, Monaco, Netherlands, Norway, Portugal, San Marino, Spain, Sweden, and Switzerland.

EASTERN EUROPE
* Not using PR: Albania, Ukraine
* Using PR: Bulgaria, Croatia, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Romania, Russia (50%), Slovakia, Slovenia
* Unknown: Byelarus, Bosnia, Macedonia, Moldovia, Serbia

MIDDLE EAST -- currently under research
* Not democracies: Syria (1 party), Iraq (1 party), Saudi Arabia (monarchy), Iran (religious), Kuwait (monarchy)
* Not using PR: --
* Using PR: Yemen (1993)
* Unknown: Jordan, Qatar, Turkey

ASIA -- currently under research.
* Not democracies: China (1 party), Laos, N. Korea (1 party), Burma (military), Vietnam (1 party)
* Not PR: India, S. Korea (21% PR), Sri Lanka (some PR), Taiwan (25% PR)
* PR: Cambodia, Indonesia (80%), Japan (40%), Mongolia?, Philipines?
* Unknown: Bahrain, Bhutan, Brunei, Fiji, Kazakstan, Maldives, Myanmar?, Oman, Pakistan, Samoa, Singapore, Soloman Islands, Tajikistan, Tonga

AUSTRALIA and nearby countries -- currently under research
* Not using PR: New Guinea
* Using PR: Australia (about 50%), New Zealand

Australia has two Federal houses of parliament, five "states" with two houses of parliament each, and one "state" and two "territories" with a single house of parliament each. Of these fifteen houses, nine have single member districts and use IRV, the other six have multi-member districts (many are one large district) and use the STV form of PR.

AFRICA: -- under research * Not democracies: Algeria (military), Libya (1 party), Somalia (civil war)
* Not using PR: ?
* Using PR: Angola, Gabon?, Madagascar, Mozambique, Senegal, South Africa
* Unknown: Benin, Botswana, Burnikina Faso, Burundi, Cameroon, Cape Verde, Central African Republic, Chad, Congo, Egypt, Equitorial Guinea, Ethopia, Ghana, Guinea, Ivory Coast, Kenya, Mali, Morocco, Namimbia, Nigeria, Sierra Leone, Somalia, Sudan, Togo, Uganda, Zaire, Zimbabwe

NORTH AMERICA, CENTRAL AMERICA and CARIBBEAN
* Not democracies: Cuba (1 party), Guatemala (military)
* Not using PR: Antigua/Bahamas, Barbados, Canada, Grenada, Haiti, Jamaica, St. Christopher, St. Lucia, St. Vincent, Trinadad & Tobago, USA
* Using PR: Costa Rica, Dominican Republic, El Salvador, Guyana, Mexico (about 65% as of 1994), Nicaragua, Panama
* Unknown: Bahamas, Barbados, Belize, Dominicana, Honduras, Virgin Islands

SOUTH AMERICA -- We understand that almost all democracies in S. America are now using PR.
* Not democracies: ?
* Not using PR: ?
* Using PR: Argentina, Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Columbia, (Butch Aruba), (Dutch Antilles), Costa Rica (with Presidential System), Ecuador, (French Guadalope), (French Guiana), (French Martinique), Guyana, Peru, Surinam, Uruguay, Venezuela
* Unknown: Paraguay

[By and large, this is pretty accurate. The Center for Voting and Democracy (CVD) has another list which is more accurate and complete, albeit in a different format, and only available by postal mail. You can e-mail CVD or via their web site

[Info modified 1/2001]


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #15

Q. What are the advantages of PR?

A. One result of PR is opening up the political process. Without PR, democracies tend to either be two party systems (e.g. USA), or 3 party systems in which the majority party, the party in control, does not actually have the support of the majority of the people in that country (e.g. the United Kingdom, Canada). With PR, depending on the type of PR and the specific country, there are usually around 7 or 8 parties, and they usually form stable coaltion governments. Now, if you think the two-party system is a good thing, then you should oppose PR, because it would surely result in a multi-party system. But, if you, like most Americans, believe that we should have more than two parties representing America, then you should consider this a major advantage.

A second advantage is that generally speaking more people vote when PR is used. Some people claim that if we used PR here in the U.S., that our turnout would rival Europian countries typical turnout of appr. 85%. While that would be very nice, more careful studies seem to indicate that our turnout would increase more in the range of 10% to a total of about 60%. While this isn't as much as we'd like, we recognize that there are many reasons why people don't vote, only some of which have to do directly with the voting system. Finally, note that a 10% increase in voting would reverse approximately 20 years of steady declines in voter turnout.

A third advantage is that PR results in more women being elected. This has been effectively proven by several researchers, such as Professor Wilma Rule, and others.

Another advantage is that the tone of the debate in PR elections tends to be much more issue oriented, less about personalities, and thus much less negative. E.g., if the party list system or MMP systems were being used, then the discusssion tends to be about the parties' performance and platform. In preference voting, candidates need to get #2 and #3 rankings, so they cannot afford to viciously attack their opponents, or they would lose those important high rankings.

In PR systems, voters can usually vote their heart, instead of making strategic votes for fear of wasting their votes.

The evil of gerrymandering is eliminated under PR, and only under PR, because gerrymanding is a result of districts in which one candidate will be elected, and under PR there are larger, multi-member districts.

More candidates tend to run under PR, because it is easier to be a candidate when you need a smaller, more enthusiastic base of support. And the candidates can honestly address difficult issues that they might have avoided before, because if, for example you only need 10 or 20% of the vote to get elected, you can afford to be more straightforward.

PR results in majority rule, but still fairly represents minority viewpoints. This is the crux of PR, and by itself is reason enough to adopt PR.

Last but not least, PR reduces the effect of money in elections. This is because candidates can target their base, and spend money very efficiently. Every election that uses PR results in fair minority representation, even when the minority doesn't have money. (By the way, "minority" in this case does not mean just an ethnic minority, but any group that isn't the majority, such as Republicans in a liberal area, and vice-versa.)


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #16

Q. What are the disadvantages of PR?

A. Some people fear that PR will result in political instability. To a large extent, this is due to confusion with parliamentary systems, where the legislative branch chooses the executive branch, resulting in irregular enforcement of laws.

Instability occurs when a small faction quits the ruling coalition, resulting in a significan rearrangement of the balance of power. It occurred when Senator Jim Jeffords quit the Republican Party in 2001. It could have also occurred if a far-right-wing senator had decided that the party was being too liberal in its efforts to maintain power.

PR tends to (but does not always) result in multi-party or multi-faction legislatures, and it can be more difficult for a legislature to reorganize itself after such a power shift. However, this difficulty is usually more a result of specific procedural rules of the legislature rather than PR itself. A few PR governments, most famously Italy and Israel (which are also both parliamentary), tend to have trouble with this, but the vast majority of them do not.

One large disadvantage is that it is a change! While some might see this as an advantage, any change involves some costs. E.g., we have to educate election administrators and companies that suppy election equipment to support more types of voting, and different ballots, than they currently are used to.

Some forms of PR require the existence of political parties. Some people are uncomfortable with the idea of making government and the democratic process dependent on such private organizations, and there are many first-amendment issues associated with this.

In California, it's already too late, because our state constitution requires the existence of parties and the use of partisan primary elections, even though PR is not widely used. Furthermore, PR would result in more parties and more competition between them, so any feared abuses would be less likely, and there would be more alternatives for a voter to choose from. And some PR methods are nonpartisan.

One concern that is raised is that the U.S. Constitution would have to be amended to allow PR. However, that is not correct. PR could be used in House elections simply by modifying the Voting Rights Act to allow PR to be used. In fact, such a bill has been introduced in the House from 1996-1998, by Cynthia McKinney (D-GA).

Another concern is that people would lose local representation, because PR is used in multi-member districts, not single-member districts. There are two ways of addressing this concern. One is to use MMP, which is a mixed-system that has local representation, and the other is to use fairly small multi-member districts. In any case, most people care about issues more than geography these days -- the current system forces representation based on where you live, not how you feel about issues.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #2

Q. How can I become part of the movement for PR?

A. Join us! Californians for Electoral Reform (CfER)
Email
CfER
PO Box 128; Sacramento, CA 95812
510/527-8025
916/967-0300
415/751-4474
408/688-8692

$25 for a regular membership, $6 for low income, $40 for Donor memberships. Groups can also join for $20. Regular membership includes a newsletter, and the national newsletter from CVD (see below). To join, send an email to the above address, including your name, address and phone number. Indicate that you are joining. You will be signed up, and billed. If you change your mind, just write "cancel" on the bill.

If you are not from California and would like to start an effort in your area, contact:
Center for Voting and Democracy (CVD)
6905 5th St NW, Ste. 200; Washington, DC 20012 301/270-4616 cvdusa@aol.com
Call or email for information


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #20

Q. What non-governmental groups/organizations use choice voting or instant runoff voting?

We are aware of the following non-governmental groups and organizations that use choice voting. This list is definitely incomplete, because we regularly hear of more groups that are using it. If you know of any other groups that are using preference voting, please email us!info@fairvoteca.org

The ACLU of Washington State voted in May of 1999 to use Choice Voting and IRV for election of officers and to select delegates to their national convention. Also, the National ACLU uses a form of cumulative voting for electing it's officers. For more information, contact John Gear: catalyst (at) mail.pacifier.com.

The Academy of Motion Picture Arts and Sciences' Academy Award nominations have been using Choice Voting since the 1930's, because they found it provides for more diversity in the nominations. They use a pure hand count. For more information, contact Bruce Davis, Executive Director, at 310/247-3000.

The American Geophysical Union (professional society for all of the geophysical sciences) uses IRV for electing all of its officers; it is specified in the bylaws. http://www.agu.org/
American Geophysical Union, 2000 Florida Ave, N.W., Washington DC 20009
(202)-462-6900 / 1-800-966-2481

American Mensa uses Choice Voting and MPV. They use a hand count. Contact Brewster Gillette at 503/245-3707, or Mensa headquarters at 817/332-2600.

The American Political Science Association ( http://apsanet.org/governance/constitution.html) uses IRV to elect its president. Sadly, the Association uses block voting to elect its board.

The American Psychological Association (website: http://www.apa.org) uses "preferential" voting to elect their president as well as their board of directors. The APA bylaws that lay out election procedures for the Board of Directors and Officers appear at:
http://www.apa.org/governance/bylaws/art7.html
http://www.apa.org/governance/bylaws/art8.html
American Psychological Association, Election Office
750 First Street, NE; Washington, DC 20002-4242 : (202) 336-6072

The Associated Students of the California Institute of Technology (ASCIT) uses IRV to elect its officers for many years. Check out Article VIII in the ASCIT By-Laws.

The Associated Students of the University of California

The Association of State Green Parties will use Choice Voting, we are told. They formed in 1997. Contact: Hank Chapot, hchapot (at) igc.apc.org.

The Boston chapter of the Black Radical Congress uses PR.

The California League of Conservation Voters (www.ecovote.org) uses preference voting to elect its two staff member board positions.

Californians for Electoral Reform (formerly Californians for Proportional Representation) has been using Choice Voting to elect its nine member Board of Directors since its inception in 1993. Voters vote by mail with a standard paper ballot, then ChoicePlus is used to tally the election. Contact: Elections Director Dave Kadlecek at 510/763-3515, dkadlecek (at) igc.apc.org.

Starting in spring of 2003, the Student Assembly ath the College of William and Mary (http://www.wm.edu/SO/studentassembly/) will be using for all elections. This includes SA President, Senators, and other class officers.

Fiji used IRV (which they apparently call "preferential voting") for the first time in 1999.

The Green Party of California and most of its locals use IRV for their internal affairs, such as electing officers. For more information, contact Tom Stafford at tstaff (at) rain.org.

The Georgia Green Party uses Choice Voting for internal elections. For more information please contact Hugh Esco at hesco (at) mindspring.com.

The Green Party of Seattle uses "preference/choice balloting" to elect five of the seven Coordinating Council members. The elected secretary and treasurer also get seats on the Coordinating Council. The GPoS also uses IRV in candidate endorsements.

The 36th District Green Party of WA State uses preference/choice balloting to elect three of its five coordinating council members, with the secretary and treasurer also getting seats.

The Harvard/Radcliffe Undergraduate Council (student government organization at Harvard and Radcliffe) uses the STV form of PR for its Council and Officers. See the bylaws at www.hcs.harvard.edu/~hruc/constbylaws.

We have been told that International Training in Communcations, a group similar to Toastmasters, uses preference voting. Their address is PO Box 92803, Anaheim, CA 92803.

John Hopkins University used Instant Run-off Voting for its freshman student council elections for the first time in the fall of 1999.

KPFA (http://www.kpfa.org), the Berkeley flagship station of the listener-sponsored Pacifica Network, uses Choice Voting in its listener elections of their Local Advisory Board. They use a modified version that ensures a balance of race and gender.

Lane Community College, in Oregon, just voted in 1997 to use Choice Voting. Contact: Kevin Hornbuckle, kevinh (at) efn.org, 503/485-2474.

The Miami University (Ohio) Faculty Senate has used ranked choice voting for some time for its Faculty Senate.  For more info contact Phil Macklin at macklipa (at) muohio.edu.

The Minnesota State Bar Association adopted STV/choice voting for use in its internal elections. This decision was made by the Board of Governors in mid-September 2000, with recommendation from a study committee that favored it as a means of diversifying the leadership of the organization

The National Organization of Women uses IRV in electing its national officers and it is "permissible" in electing the national board members from each region. See Article VI.5 and Article VII.5.B at http://209.207.163.32/organiza/bylaws.html

The Onion River Food Cooperative in Burlington, Vermont, used Choice Voting for their board elections in November 1999. For more information, contact Terry Bouricius at klamb (at) brownsriver.k12.vt.us or at 802/864-8382.

Pacific Green Party of Oregon uses PR (Choice Voting) to elect its Coordinating Committee. Contact Fillard Rhyne at 503/777-0117 for more info.

The Reform Party will use IRV to select its Presidential candidate for the November 2000 general election. For more information go to www.reformparty.org/candidates/nominations.html..

Stanford University has been using Choice Voting for its academic elections (Senate, Steering Committee, and Advisory Board) since at least 1973.  For more information, contact JC Bangert at jbangert (at) stanford.edu. Beginning in 2001, the student government (ASSU) will use IRV for presidential elections -- contact Dave Robinson at dbr (at) stanford.edu for more information. The Grad Student Council and Undergraduate Senate still use plurality voting.

The University of Illinois Math Department Councils have been elected with Choice Voting since the late 1950's. The vote is tallied using a computer program written by Jim Parr, who is associated with the university. Contact: Jim Parr, parr (at) arachnic.match.ilstu.edu.

We are told that the University of Texas Graduate Assembly uses preference voting, and that interested parties should contact Dr. Robert Jeffrey for more information (but we weren't given a telephone number, postal address, or email address!).

The World Science Fiction Society uses IRV to select the winner of the Hugo award in each category. For more information see: worldcon.org.

York High School in Monterey, California, uses IRV for its student government elections.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #21 -- Doesn't Arrow's Theorem prove that voting is flawed?

Arrow's Theorem and many derivative works show that just about any set of criteria that one would think essential for any voting procedure (for example: adding an extra losing candidate should not affect the outcome, there should be no built-in bias for or against a candidate, a single individual should not have all the power, a unanimously preferred candidate should win) is self-contradictory. This reflects the fundamental principle of economics: you can't please all the people all the time.

A PR voting method cannot escape the basic laws of economics, but it is certainly more efficient at providing every voter a representative s/he supports than any other procedure in use today.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #22

Q. What Software is Available to count PR Elections?

The DemoChoice web poll system is an open-source, cross-platform package for tallying preference voting elections.

ChoicePlus by Voting Solutions is a commercial package that has been used to tally public preference voting elections in Cambridge, MA and elsewhere.

Other programs have been written and used to count non-governmental PR elections, or for research purposes. According to Jim Lindsay, "Writing a program to count a Choice Voting election is not really that difficult. Any competent programmer can do it. However, writing one that is stable, supports a wide variety of options, is fast, and produces a number of reports, etc., is not at all a trivial task."

If you've written software to count PR elections, and you'd like to be listed here, email us!


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #23

Q. What Hardware is Available to count PR Elections?

In general, there are three types of voting machines: DRE (direct recording entry machines, or electronic voting machines), marksense (fill in the bubble), punch card systems. The old lever system might have been considered DRE, and a fair number of rural areas still do manual voting.

Electronic voting machines have been the most friendly to PR activists. It is easy for them to support preference voting. Marksense companies are somewhat friendly -- some can handle PV, some can't yet. Punch card companies tend to be somewhat hostile.

However, punch card systems are being replaced at an increasing rate, and it seems that almost all companies are now providing some sort of marksense or DRE solution.

Global Elections Systems (604/261-6313, now owned by Diebold) is the vendor that serves Cambridge. Their system has been used successfully since 1997. Sequoia Pacific Systems (704/487-0161) has the New York upgrading contract, and I'm told they are supporting preference voting due to its use for the school committees there.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #26

Question: Isn't PR the same as the Parliamentary System?

Not at all! A parliamentary system is a way to organize government. PR is a way to choose representatives.

In nearly all jurisdictions of the United States, we have separation of legislative and executive powers. This insulates the process of executing the laws from the changing tides in the legislature as issues are confronted and debated. A parliamentary system has no such separation: the legislature controls the executive power. In some cases, this results in unstable execution of laws, as has been seen in Israel and Italy.

You can have PR under presidential or parliamentary systems. They should never be confused.

The Differences Between Parliamentary and Presidential Systems

  Pure Parliamentary Pure Presidential
Head of government chosen Head of majority party or coalition in parliament Elected by popular vote
Title of head of government Usually "Prime Minister" "President"
Head of state chosen Varies; Often hereditary, but also often elected by parliament, popular vote, or in an electoral college Same as head of government
Title of head of state Usually "President," "King," or "Queen" Same as head of government
Powers of president Miminal, mostly ceremonial (if there is a president at all) Moderate to high -- appoints cabinet (maybe with legislators' consent), can fire cabinet at will, usually can veto legislation
Can legislative majority dismiss the head of government? Yes -- whenever it loses "confidence" in the government No -- not for political reasons, only on finding of impeachable offense
Can government fall between elections? Yes, as a result of no-confidence vote No -- president has fixed term
Can early elections be called? Usually No -- legislature, like executive, has fixed term

TABLE OF COUNTRIES USING DIFFERENT SYSTEMS

  ELECTORAL SYSTEM TYPE
CONSTITUTIONAL TYPE PR Mixed, leaning towards PR Mixed, leaning towards WTA WTA
Pure Parliamentary Most European democracies, South Africa, Australian Senate New Zealand Hungary, Italy, Japan Australian House, Canada, India, Jamaica, United Kingdom
Mixed, leaning towards parliamentary 1 Austria, Bulgaria, Finland, Poland, Portugal, Romania   Macedonia, Mongolia France, Haiti
Mixed/Intermediate Israel 2      
Mixed, leaning towards presidential 3 Sri Lanka   Armenia, Russia  
Pure Presidential Most Latin American democracies Bolivia, Venezuela Georgia (the ex-Soviet republic), Phillipines, S. Korea, Mexico Nigeria, USA
  1. These cases lean parliamentary because the cabinet, headed by a prime minister, must maintain the confidence of the legislature. There is a popularly elected president , but he or she cannot dismiss a cabinet that enjoys the confidence of the legislature (as in a presidential system). Most of them--Poland and Mongolia are exceptions--also cannot veto laws passed by the legislature. In some of these countries, the president has the authority, under certain conditions, to dissolve parliament and call early elections.
  2. In Israel, the system has some "presidential" features in that the head of government (called "Prime Minister") is directly elected. But it also has some "parliamentary" features in that the Prime Minister and cabinet may be dismissed by a vote of no confidence passed by a majority of the parliament (called "Knesset"). When that happens, early elections are held for both parliament and prime minister.
  3. These cases lean presidential because the president may appoint and dismiss the prime minister at his or her pleasure. However, because they have a prime minister who also may be dismissed by the legislature, and have provisions allowing the president to dissolve the legislature under some conditions, they are not "pure" presidential.

Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #27

"Isn't PR based on a quota system? Wouldn't that be very divisive?"

No! This is, unfortunately, a common misconception about PR. PR is 100% race neutral, and 100% gender neutral. PR has *nothing* to do with quotas of any sort.

Our current system of at-large local elections combined with large, single member districts for state and national campaigns does an excellent job of representing majority parties and majority ethnicities. The current system does *not* fairly represent minority parties and minority ethnicities. PR, however, fairly represents both majorities and minorities. Majority rule + fair representation for all = PR.

In addition, our current system unfairly encourages the overrepresentation of men at the state and national level. I refer you to the work of political science professors Rule, Darcy, Welch, Clark, Lakeman, and Shugart for more information about this. But the gist of it is this: If we are serious about fair representation for women, we need PR.

Simply because it is a more sophisticated system, and not due to any quotas or predetermined results, PR would better reflect the diversity that helps to make America great. But it would not do so due to a quota system -- rather just because with PR, who is eventually elected better reflects how people actually voted.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #28

Question: "How would PR work for the California State Assembly?"

Answer:

Applying PR to the State Assembly is easily done. Any of the three forms (MMP, Party List, and Choice Voting) could be used. The use of any of them would require a state constitutional amendment, however, since California's constitution currently mandates single-member districts for both the Assembly and State Senate.

Given that, let's look at how MMP might work. We could divide the Assembly into 40 members elected from single-member districts, and 40 elected from party lists. Each voter would have two votes for Assembly on election day, a candidate vote and a party vote. The candidate vote is cast for the person that the voter wants to represent the district, and either current pluarality rules, or Instant Runoff rules, could be used. The party vote is cast for the party that the voter wants to represent him or her in the Assembly, and does not have to be for the same party as that of the candidate whom the voter chose.

After the 40 district seats are allocated, the 40 party seats are allocated in a compensatory fashion, so that each party gets a total number of seats (district plus party) corresponding to the percentage of the party vote they received. For example, suppose the Blue Party and the Red Party each receive 10 percent of the vote, entitling each to 8 seats in the Assembly. If five Blue Party members are elected from the districts, the Blue Party gets three of the party seats seats which they fill from their list. If two Red Party members are elected from districts, they get six of the party seats.

The split doesn't have to be 40/40 to get proportionality. Reasonable proportionality can be acheived with a 60/20 split (60 from districts, 20 from party lists), if the public would prefer more representatives from districts than from the party lists.

Q. What happens if a party elects more candidates from districts than they are entitled to by the party vote? For example, suppose the Yellow Party also gets 10 percent of the vote but elects 12 people from districts? Do four of them get kicked out?

A. While rare, such a situation could happen, and any valid election law would have to cover such a case. At least two solutions are possible. In no case would you want to disallow the Yellow Party the 12 seats they won through districts; it wouldn't be fair to the voters of those districts. One possibility is to let the size of the Assembly grow temporarily (until the next election), in this case by four additional seats. The rest of the parties would still get their percentage of seats based on the nominal count of 80 seats. This is the approach taken by New Zealand. The other approach is to adjust the remaining seat allocations so that the total still comes out to 80; this means that the other parties will get slightly fewer seats than the percentages would indicate, but the relative distribution (excluding the Yellow Party) would still be the same.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #29

Q. Where is Cumulative Voting used?

Governmental Agencies
JurisdictionCountyYear of first use
Chilton County CommissionChilton AL1988
Chilton Board of EducationChilton AL1988
Centre City CouncilCherokee AL1988
Guin City CouncilMarion AL1988
Heath City CouncilCovington AL1988
Myrtlewood City CouncilMarengo AL1988
Peoria City CouncilPeoria IL1991
Alamogordo City CouncilOtero NM1987
Lovington School BoardLea NMunknown
Sisseton Board of Education(unknown county) SD1990
Abernathy City CouncilHale TX1996
Andrews City CouncilAndrews TX1996
Anton City CouncilHockley TX1995
Boerne City CouncilKendall TX1997
Earth City CouncilLamb TX1995
Friona City CouncilParmer TX1994
Hale Center City CouncilHale TX1994
Jourdonton City CouncilAtascosa TX1997
Morton City CouncilCochran TX1994
O'Donnell City CouncilLynn TX1997
Olton City CouncilLamb TX1995
Poth City CouncilWilson TX1996
Roscoe City CouncilNolan TX1995
Rotan City CouncilFisher TX1995
Yorktown City CouncilDewitt TX1992
Abernathy Ind. School Dist.Hale TX1994
Amherst Ind. School Dist.Lamb TX1996
Andrews Ind. School Dist.Andrews TX1994
Anson Ind. School Dist.Jones TX1995
Anton Ind. School Dist.Hockley TX1996
Atlanta Ind. School Dist.Cass TX1995
Big Spring Ind. School Dist.Howard TX1998
Bovina Ind. School Dist.Parmer TX1994
Denver City Ind. School Dist.Yoakum TX1994
Dumas Ind. School Dist.Moore TX1995
Friona Ind. School Dist.Parmer/Deaf Smith TX1994
Hale Center Ind. School Dist.Hale TX1994
Hamlin Ind. School Dist.Jones TX1998
Irion Co. Ind. School Dist. Irion TX1996
Lockhart Ind. School Dist.  Caldwell TX1991
Luling Ind. School Dist.Caldwell TX1996
Morton Ind. School Dist.Cochran TX1994
Navarro Ind. School Dist.Guadalupe TX1997
O'Donnell Ind. School Dist.Lynn, Dawson TX1995
Olton Ind. School Dist.Lamb TX1997
Post Ind. School Dist.Garza TX1997
Poth Ind. School Dist.Wilson TX1996
Riviera Ind. School Dist.Kleberg TX1997
Ropes Ind. School Dist.Hockley TX1997
Rotan Ind. School Dist.Fisher TX1995
Springlake-Earth Ind. School Dist.Lamb TX1995
Stamford Co. Line Ind. School Dist.Haskell, Jones TX1995
Sudan Ind. School Dist.Bailey, Lamb TX1997
Sundown Ind. School Dist.Hockley TX1997
Wilson Ind. School Dist.Lynn TX1997
Yoakum Ind. School Dist.Lavaca TX1993
Yorktown Ind. School Dist.DeWitt TX1992
Terry Co. Memorial Hosp. Dist.Terry TX1997

Non-governmental Agencies
Associated Students of Madison (ASM), which is the student government of the University of Wisconsin in Madison.

If you know of other elections where cumulative voting is used, please let us know! E-mail us at stevew@initcomp.com.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

A new web page by the Proportional Representation Society of Australia, Victoria branch.

Douglas Amy's PR Library.

The home page of the British Electoral Reform Society.

The home page of the International Institute for Democracy and Electoral Assistance.

The ACE Project - Administration and Cost of Elections.

Atlas of Electoral Systems of the World page.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page -->

CfER FAQ #30

Q. When was PR first invented?  And when was it first used?

According to Mirror of the Nation's Mind (JFH Wright, 1980, Hale & Iremonger, Sydney):

Party List was "[p]roposed by Thomas Gilpin of Philadelphia, USA, and independently by Victor Considerant, in Switzerland [no dates given], [and] it was first used in the Canton of Ticino in Switzerland in 1891." (page 47.)

The first "quota-preferential" method was "put into a workable form first by Thomas Hill, a schoolmaster in Birmingham, England, in 1821." (page 48.)  "The first public election in the world in which the principle of proportional representation was put into effect appears to have been the election of the Municipal Corporation of the City of Adelaide in 1840."  (page 93.)  This was done at the suggestion of then-Secretary of the Colonization Commission for South Australia Rowland Hill, son of the afore-mentioned Thomas Hill.  But I don't think this used a single-transferable vote, but determined the makeup of the quota in a differnt way.  The first use of single-transferable vote apparently occurred "in elections of the members from Hobart and Launceston in the Tasmanian House of Assembly in 1897."  (page 95.)

The preferential ballot "was devised around 1870 by W.R.  Ware, a Professor of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (Hare 1873, pp351-355)."  (page 35.)  "The first preferential method used in a parliamentary election in Australia [was] in Queensland in 1893" (page 34) but in that count if no one got a majority all but the top two were eliminated and the rest of the ballots transferred.  The "staggered runoff" concept that we understand today as IRV "was used first in Western Australia in 1908."  (page 34.)


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #31

Q. How does PR result in more positive, issue-oriented election campaigns?

A. The reasons why depend on the type of PR that is used.

If it is a party oriented system, such as the "party-list" or "mixed member" systems, then the discussions (and advertisements) are about the parties' platforms, performance, and history -- not about individuals. Parties may attack each other, but the attacks are not normally the ugly personal attacks that we so often see in the United States.

The other major type of PR is the Choice Voting system, in which the voter ranks his/her choices 1, 2, 3, etc. These elections tend to have positive campaigns because in order to win candidates must obtain not just #1 rankings, but also #2, #3, and even #4 rankings. So they cannot afford to attack their opponents, or they will lose lower ranking votes, and that could easily cost them the election.

You see, it is not that candidates suddenly become nicer people when PR is used. Most candidates under any electoral system would prefer to run clean, positive, and issue-oriented campaigns. The problem is that in order to win winner-take-all elections, it is very often necessary to run negative ads. Someone is going to find themselves behind in the polls, and despite best intentions, will start running hit pieces to try to narrow the gap. And it works -- if it didn't work, they'd stop doing it.

Therefore, what we must do is put in place electoral systems that encourage positive campaigns and discourage negative campaigns -- because it is just part of those systems that you need to run positive, issue-oriented campaigns to win elections. Once we have accomplished that goal, you'll actually be able to watch political advertisements without being sickened by those truly horrid hit pieces.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #4

Q. Where is PR used in the U.S. and Canada?

PR, in the form of preference voting, is currently used to elect the City Council and School Committee in Cambridgeassachusetts, and the New York City local school committees.

PR has been used in a number of cities in the past, including New York City, Cincinnati, and others. In all known cases, PR succeeded in its mission of providing majority rule with fair minority representation. However, PR was dropped in many cities in the 1950's because the hand-count was cumbersome, due to McCarthyist hysteria after a communist was elected to the city council of New York, and sometimes due to racial tensions.

A number of jurisdictions are using semi-proportional systems (Limited and Cumulative Voting).  See FAQ #29 for a list of jurisdictions using Cumulative Voting.

A number of cities are considering using PR. As of this writing (November of 1996) there are petition campaigns in Cincinnati, Ohio, Seattle, Washington, and Urbana, Illinois. A number of city commissions are studying it.

San Franciscans just voted not to adopt PR in November of 1996. In a short 3-month period activists were able to convince 44% of the voters that PR was the best system. Unfortunately, district elections had a 20 year name recognition, and voters chose to adopt them instead of PR. There is other ongoing activity in other parts of the country. [see FAQ #2 for more info].

The Canadian Wheat Board uses PR. KPMG is the company that administered the election, contact Craig Fossay cfossay@kpmg.ca for info.

The Democratic Party uses a form of PR to select its delegates to its National Convention. Each candidate represents a sort of party, and delegates to the convention are allocated in proportion to the candidate's results. To be technical, the allocation is by Congressional District, and there's a 15% threshold. So if, in a given district, Al Gore gets 55% of the vote in the Democratic Primary, Bill Bradley gets 35%, and someone else gets 10%, Gore will get about 61% of that district's delegates, and Bradley will get about 39%. For more information contact the Democratic National Committee.

The Minnesota Democratic Party uses an interesting form of Proportional Representation in presidential caucuses. Voters actually physically move around the room to represent who they are supporting. If their candidate is eliminated, they move to a different group. For more information, contact Tony Solgard: solga002@tc.umn.edu

Finally, more and more non-governmental organizations are using PR and/or preference voting [see FAQ #20].


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page

CfER FAQ #5

"What are the main types of Proportional Representation?"

"Proportional Representation" (PR) actually means using any one of several different types of election systems. The main types are "Party List", "Mixed Member Proportional", and "Choice Voting".

(There is also another, lesser well known system now being called "Interactive Representation", and several types of "semi-proportional" systems such as cumulative voting and limited voting.)

PARTY LIST

In a "Party-List" system, voters vote for their favorite party. If a party gets 40% of the vote, it gets 40% of the seats. If it gets 10% of the vote, it gets 10% of the seats. Each party submits a list of candidates to the voters. If 100 seats are to be filled, and a party gets 10% of the votes, it will get 10 seats.

Which 10 candidates get the seats? In most countries, people can select their favortie candidates from the list, and whoever gets the most votes within that party will get elected. That is called an "open-list" system. In a few countries, you just fill the seats from the top of the list. That is called a "closed-list" system.

In almost all party-list system, there is a threshold that must be met before a party wins any seats at all. This typically ranges from 2% - 4%. This is to prevent extremist and very small parties from winning seats, and to avoid having too many parties and a fractured legislature. Incidentally, Israel and Italy (before it recently changed its system) are two of the countries that have either no threshold, or a very low threshold.

Some countries that use Party list systems are: Germany, Norway, Sweden, Finland, Austria, Italy, Spain, Portugal, South Africa, Israel, Cambodia, and Japan. There are many more. This is the most common type of PR in the world.

The biggest advantage of Party List PR is that it is very simple. Perhaps the biggest disadvantage, in least in the USA, is that it is purely party based, and Americans are not exactly enamored with parties right now.

MIXED MEMBER PROPORTIONAL

The second major type of PR is Mixed Member Proportional, or MMP for short. It is also known as "Personalized PR", The "Additional Member" system, and sometimes as the "German PR" system.

In this system, which is growing in popularity, about half of the members of the legislature are elected from single-seat districts, while the other half of the seats are filled via the party list vote.

Each voter has two votes: the first vote is who s/he wants to represent their district. The second vote is who his/her favorite party is. For example, a voter in North Caroline might vote for Jesse Helms as his representative, and the Republican Party as his favorite party.

After all of the district elections are finished, the party-list seats are allocated, in a manner such that the overall representation is based on each parties overall vote. E.g.: Let us say that there are 500 members of parliament. 250 seats will be filled from districts, and 250 seats will be filled from the party lists. The Christian Democrats got 40% of the vote, and elected 159 people in districts. The Conservative Party got 35% of the vote, and elected 90 people in districts. The Green Party got 5% of the vote, and elected no one from districts. The Free Democrats got 9% of the vote, and elected one person in a district. The Reform Party got 11% of the vote, and elected no one from districts.

Since the Christian Democracts got 40% of the vote, they deserve 40% of the seats, or 200 seats. They have 159 seats already (from the district elections), so they get 41 more seats from their party list to bring their total to 200. The Conservatives (35%) get 85 additional seats, which added to their 90, makes 175 seats. The Greens get 25 seats, all from their list, since they didn't win in any districts. The Free Democrats get 44 additional seats, plus their 1 district seat, for a total of 45%. Finally the Reform Party gets 55 seats, all from their list.

MMP is growing in popularity, because it combines district representation with proportional representation. It was first used in Germany, but has spread to New Zealand, while variations of it are now used in Russia, Mexico, and Japan. Perhaps its biggest disadvantage is that it is more complicated than Party List PR. Also, unless you increase the size of the legislature, each district will have to be twice its current size.

CHOICE VOTING

In choice voting, you, as a voter, do not vote for parties. You vote for individuals. You rank each candidate in order by choice (or preference). If you like Smith best, then you put a #1 by her name. If you like Garcia second best, then you put a #2 by her name, etc. Each voter has a total of 1 vote. The reason the ballot is ranked in order of preference is so that your vote is not wasted if your favorite candidate does not win. If Smith doesn't win, your vote is not wasted -- it goes to Garcia. Also, if Smith is very popular, and gets more votes then she needed to get elected, some of your vote will go to Garcia anyway. The bottom line is that you get to just walk into the voting booth and vote your heart -- no more agonizing over who might win, worrying about wasting your vote, etc. For example, if we had used this system in the last presidential election, those who liked Ross Perot best would have put a #1 by his name, and then a #2 by their second favorite candidate. Vote your heart, but don't waste your vote!

To get elected, a candidate must get a certain number of votes. For example, if there are nine council members to be elected, each winner needs about 1/9th of the vote, or about 10%, to win. Once they get those votes, they are elected.

This system is used in Australia, Ireland, and Malta. In the United States it is used in Cambridge for its city council and school board. It is also used for many non-governmental elections in Britain and the United States. For example, the Church of England uses it, and the Academy Award nominations uses it.

This system is also known as "Preference Voting", "Single Transferable Voting", "STV", and "PR/STV". "STV" is the more scientific and precise name, while "Choice Voting" is the more popular name.

This systems greatest advantage is that it allows the voter the greatest flexibility, and it diminishes the importance of parties, since voters vote for candidates, not parties. Its greatest disadvantage is that because it is a sophisticated system, it is harder to explain to people.

SUMMARY

Each of these systems has advantages and disadvantages. But the bottom line is that they are all much better than our current "winner-take-all" system. Each PR system provides for majority rule, but with fair minority representation. Each system makes the voters' votes more powerful -- very few votes are wasted in PR. Only PR can get rid of gerrymandering once and for all. Only with PR will you have more positive, issue-oriented election campaigns. Any of these sytems will achieve these ends.

There is a lot more that can be said about each of these systems. If you'd like more detailed informaton, just email us, and we'll answer within 48 hours, or double your money back.


Back to FAQ Index
CfER Home Page