Of the counting methods presented here, we consider the following questions:
The chart shows a striking result: less than half of votes cast counted toward a winner! This means that, even if the city council made a unanimous decision, it would not satisfy the third principle by representing a mandate of a majority of voters. A comparable number of voters chose not to support any of the eligible candidates in their district (listed here as "votes for eliminated candidates"). Also, inequity on the council is very large. The least popular candidate earned a seat with less than one sixth of the number of votes for the most popular candidate. |
Given the time and expense invested in the runoff election, the improvement shown in the chart is not very impressive. A few more votes were cast toward winners, and a few more were cast to eliminated candidates. The entire council still does not have a mandate from a majority of voters. The least popular winner had slightly more than (as opposed to less than) one sixth of the votes of the most popular winner. |
The At-Large method shows some advantages over single-member districts in this election. 68 percent of votes were cast toward a winner, and the last-place winner had about two thirds the number of votes as the first-place winner. |
The catch is that there is a large inequity among voters. The bar chart shows that some people helped elect seven, eight, or even nine candidates while many helped elect one or zero. With some cooperation, it would have been possible for less than half of voters to elect the entire council. |
Despite its simplicity and bleak name, this method performs quite well. 77 percent of votes were cast toward a winner. The first-place winner received more than twice as many votes as the last-place winner. |
The 100/(n+1) number is used because it is the lowest possible value that prevents election of too many candidates.
The additional complexity of this method pays off well: 93 percent of votes
counted toward a winner. This is so high that a majority of votes on the council (5)
can be fairly described as a mandate from a majority of voters. Preferential voting
methods are the only ones presented here that can routinely and genuinely satisfy the
majority principle. Power on the council is distributed very fairly: six candidates were elected with exactly the same number of votes. The remaining three received an extra 5-15 percent from an eliminated candidate. This method is as close as they get to truly proportional representation. |
One more question:
Dave Robinson - Aug 2001